Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • View all journals
  • My Account Login
  • Explore content
  • About the journal
  • Publish with us
  • Sign up for alerts
  • Open access
  • Published: 17 February 2021

Urbanization and economic complexity

  • Riccardo Di Clemente   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0001-8005-6351 1 , 2 ,
  • Emanuele Strano 3 &
  • Michael Batty 2  

Scientific Reports volume  11 , Article number:  3952 ( 2021 ) Cite this article

15k Accesses

24 Citations

25 Altmetric

Metrics details

  • Applied mathematics
  • Complex networks
  • Statistical physics

Urbanization plays a crucial role in the economic development of every country. The mutual relationship between the urbanization of any country and its economic productive structure is far from being understood. We analyzed the historical evolution of product exports for all countries using the World Trade Web with respect to patterns of urbanization from 1995 to 2010. Using the evolving framework of economic complexity, we reveal that a country’s economic development in terms of its production and export of goods, is interwoven with the urbanization process during the early stages of its economic development and growth. Meanwhile in urbanized countries, the reciprocal relation between economic growth and urbanization fades away with respect to its later stages, becoming negligible for countries highly dependent on the export of resources where urbanization is not linked to any structural economic transformation.

Similar content being viewed by others

research paper on urban economics

Complex economic activities concentrate in large cities

research paper on urban economics

Commuting network effect on urban wealth scaling

research paper on urban economics

Projecting future populations of urban agglomerations around the world and through the 21st century

Introduction.

It is an established fact that urbanization in developed countries is accompanied by economic growth and industrialization which mutually self-reinforce one another 1 . This historic pattern generates an expectation of a virtuous circle between economic growth and urbanization regardless of local conditions 2 , 3 . From classic urban economic theories 4 , 5 to the more recent scaling approach to cities 6 , 7 , the growth of urban population has routinely been used as a proxy for economic growth. This pattern has also been observed in rapidly developing countries such as China and India but it cannot be considered a universal blueprint 8 for deviations from this norm have not yet been fully explained.

In fact, as pointed out in several studies 9 , 10 , 11 , 12 , the increasing urbanization rate in persistently poor and non-industrialized countries poses an important dilemma for urban economic theory. Why, given the same rate of urbanization, does Asia contain a number of explosive economies while sub-Saharan Africa has seen very little growth? Moreover, in developed and advanced industrialized economies, is there appears to be a competitive advantage in continuing this urbanization process indefinitely?

There are several theories aimed at explaining urbanization processes. Some argue that rural poverty moves people to cities as was clearly the case in nineteenth century Europe and America 13 , driving the transformation from an agricultural to an industrial-service based economy 14 , 15 . Others argue that in the last decades there has been urban-biased public policy that has led to over-urbanization 12 .

The most intriguing approach however is rooted in the mutual indirect effects of the World Trade Web (WTW) on global urbanization 16 , 17 . The dominant idea is that in open economies, domestic communities (such as cities) can trade easily with other communities, boosting their exports in substituting industrialization for urbanization policy 18 . In simple terms, the commodities can flow more freely using urban agglomerates as nodes in the trading networks between countries, generating the ever present virtuous circle between economic growth and urbanization.

Starting from this theory, we analyze the WTW to explore the mutual relationship between the urbanization of the countries and their economic production structure using the Economic Complexity (EC) framework. Economic Complexity 19 , 20 , 21 , 22 , 23 , 24 , 25 , 26 , 27 , is a new and expanding field in the economic analysis, which proposes “Fitness” and “Complexity” metrics to quantify the fitness or competitiveness of countries and the complexity of products from a country’s basket of exports. The main focus of EC is based on a bipartite representation of the World Trade Web where the nodes represent the set of world-countries and the set of exported products defined as different entities. Countries and products are connected to one another by imposing a threshold based on their Revealed Comparative Advantage (RCA) 28 which defines the criterion for the existence of relations.

The Fitness and Complexity algorithm is a kind of PageRank method applied to WTW, where Fitness \(F_c\) is the quantity for country c , and Complexity \(Q_p\) is the quantity for products p . The idea at the basis of the algorithm is that the countries with the highest fitness are those which are able to export the highest number of the most exclusive products i.e. those with the highest complexity. On the other hand this complexity is non linearly related to the fitness of its exporters so that products exported by low fitness countries have a low level of complexity and high complexity products are exported by high fitness countries only.

The Fitness metric is valuable in quantifying a country’s productive structure and structural transformations which enable one to predict its future economic growth 23 . It correlates with the extent of economic equality 29 and it has been used to analyze the country’s growth path to industrialization 30 .

In this work, we used a data driven approach borrowing tools recently introduce by statistical physics and network science to improve our understanding of the complex dynamics of human societies, with the aim of finding innovative insight 31 to link urbanization process with the evolution of the international trade.

We couple the WTW data with the urbanization level of more than 144 countries worldwide, and analyze this between 1995-2010 thus capturing the fingerprint of urbanization on countries’ productive systems through the lens of their exports. We notice that in rural economies, the increase in urban population fosters structural changes in industrial exports. It boosts the country’s diversification improving the country fitness, and allowing the export of more complex products. These economic transformations fade away in countries that already have a high level of urban population (more than \(60\%\) ) where there is no relation between the urbanization process and the country’s fitness.

Within the sub-Saharan countries, we capture those where the virtuous circle between economic growth and urbanization is fostering structural changes in those countries’ productive systems. On the other hand within countries with economies based on raw materials, we assess the implementation of policy leading to urbanization that does not support any structural transformations of their basket of exports.

Economic complexity and urbanization

We represent the WTW as a bipartite network, i.e. by considering the set of world-countries and the set of products as different entities and linking a given country to a given product if (and only if) the former exports to the latter above a certain threshold (the so-called Revealed Comparative Advantage—RCA) 28 . RCA is a general criterion adopted in order to understand whether a country can be considered, or not, a producer of a particular product. It quantifies how much the export of a given product p is relevant for the economy of a country c in relation to the global export of p for all countries (See “ Methods ” Section).

The country’s fitness and product’s complexity are the result of a non-linear iterative map applied to the WTW matrix M 19 , 20 , 32 (See “ Methods ”).

Through the algorithm’s iterations, products exported by low fitness countries have a low level of complexity while high complexity products are exported by high fitness countries only. The countries’ composition of their export basket depends on their fitness. Fitness and Complexity are thus non-monetary indicators of the economy’s development: the fitness represents a measure of tangible and intangible assets and capabilities, which drive the country’s development, such as political organization, its history, geography, technology, services, and infrastructures 21 . Meanwhile complexity measures the necessary capabilities which must be owned by a country in order that it can produce and then export the resulting product.

Within this framework, we include the dimension of a country’s degree of urbanization defined as the percentage of the total population living in urban areas. Our aim is to quantify the link between a country’s urbanization process and their exports as a proxy for their industrial economic system. To disentangle the relation between country productivity systems and their urbanization, we have divided the set of countries in terms of their degree of urbanization, defined by the Urban Range, which is expressed in four quantiles [ Q 1,  Q 2,  Q 3,  Q 4] (see urban range division in Fig.  1 B top).

figure 1

( A ) Distribution of exported products complexity by different urbanization levels through the 2000–2010. There is a shift of lower urbanized countries towards the export of more complex products ( B ) Distribution of the Urban Range (percentage of the total population living in urban areas) of the 144 countries analyzed. ( B ) Ranked country fitness versus products export diversification, the highly diversified countries are one’s with more fitness and high urbanization, meanwhile low urbanized country are in the center bottom of the scatter plot, with some exceptions such as those with links to the oil countries. ( C ) Matrix of the country exports in 2010, reordering the countries and products by fitness and complexity; the color dots represent an exported product under the RCA threshold Eq. ( 2 ), the color gradient follows the urban range definition.

More urbanized countries [Q3,Q4] in the early 2000s, export a wide range of complex products such as: textiles, heavy manufacturing industries, and IT while rural countries [Q1,Q2] export products that require a low level of sophistication such as raw materials and agricultural products (Fig.  1 A).

Highly urbanized countries maintain a similar distribution across the analysis years, with a long tail of low complexity products and a consistent increase in the number of high complexity products. On the other hand starting from 2005, we have noticed that rural countries change their export basket towards higher complexity products. This shift is shown by the cumulative distribution functions of the different Urban ranges that decrease their distance from one another over time (see Fig.  1 A inset) together with their median and peak distance.

We notice that countries within the higher quantile of the Urban Range, Fig.  1 B, are the ones with higher fitness and higher diversification, whilst low urbanized countries have a low diversification and fitness. Notable exceptions are countries with exports based on raw materials (i.e. Qatar, Kuwait, Gabon, Iraq, Libya). These countries reached higher levels of urbanization as result of policy decisions 33 meanwhile their exports are limited to a few products with low complexity.

The representation of the WTW in Fig.  1 C shows country exports in 2010 rearranged by ranked fitness and complexity. The country exports’ diversification is related to the urbanization level. Low urbanized countries are at the bottom of the matrix with low fitness and lower degree of diversification, whilst the urbanized countries, with the most advanced economies lie at the top, with a high degree of product diversification with different levels of complexity and high fitness.

Exports diversification and urbanization

It is known that low fitness countries have similar economies with low degrees of diversification and high similarity with respect to their export baskets 20 , 34 , 35 i. e. they produce and export few of the same low technology products. We captured a shift in the distribution of the exported products within the rural countries (Fig.  1 A). In particular, we noticed that rural countries start to produce and export more sophisticated products. This productive systems transformation in the EC literature is related to the development of new capabilities 22 , 36 , 37 .

Some questions from this analysis emerge: do the rural countries evolve their productive systems in the same way? and do they continue to produce and export the same products? Is the pattern of economic development entangled with urbanization in same fashion for each rural country?

We can measure indirectly the transformation of the productive systems by analyzing the evolution of WTW topology 38 . In particular we can assess the changes of countries’ similarities in their exports studying the abundance evolution of network motifs 39 . A network motif is a particular pattern of interconnections occurring between the nodes of the network (i.e. between the countries and their products). In our case we are interested in the abundance of the similarity motif \(\mu _{sim}\) in Fig.  2 B (motifs 6 40 , or X motif 35 ): it quantifies the co-occurrence of any two countries as producers of the same couple of products as Eq. ( 7 ) (and, viceversa, the co-occurrence of any two products in the basket of the same couple of countries). This represents the simplest motifs 40 that can quantify the similarities in the export countries’ diversification which maintains a pairwise correlation within the products exported. Two economies with a fixed number of products exported are diversifying if the values of \(\mu _{sim}\) is decreasing while their production similarity increases with high values of \(\mu _{sim}\) .

figure 2

( A ) Z-score of the export similarity motif by country groups with different Urban Ranges and the Z-score of the whole WTW in black. ( B ) Similarity motif as the co-occurrence of any two countries as producers of the same couple of products 35 , 40 .

To provide a benchmark and asses the \(\mu _{sim}\) statistical significance of the WTW we use the Bipartite Configuration Model (BiCM) 34 as a null model. This framework is valuable in the analysis of the abundance of the bipartite motifs 40 , enabling us to detect financial crisis effects on a country’s export basket 35 as well as export similarities between countries with same level of economic development 41 .

We generated 1000 matrices using the BiCM 34 (see “ Methods ” Section) and we compare the observed abundances of the similarity motif (Eq. 7 ) in the real network with the corresponding expected values in the null ensemble using the Z-score.

The whole WTW manifests a progressive increase of the abundance of similarity motifs with respect to the null case 35 (Black line Fig.  2 A). Highly urbanized countries show a similar trend of increasing similarity in their products exports. This measure implies that rural economies are very similar with a higher abundance of the similarity motif with respect to the random case having a high value Z-score. Interestingly, low urban range countries diversifying between each other manifest an opposite trend. The exports diversification trends of the low urbanized countries coupled with the increasing complexity of the product exported imply a nontrivial connection between urbanization and production capabilities. This measure outlines how rural economies follow different development patterns based on their production systems. The urbanization phenomenon coupled with the capabilities already presented in the country enable the production of different sophisticated products depending on their environment.

Urbanization growth and country fitness

The economic transformation of a rural country has an impact on its overall fitness value, and the competitiveness of its productive system. In this respect, the urbanization process is key element in a country’s development and its economic growth 33 , 42 . To assess the relation between the country’s fitness and the urbanization process we analyzed the Urban Range growth rate in relation to the growth rate of country fitness ranking between 1995 and 2010, as we show in Fig.  3 . The country fitness ranking is the country’s ordered position with respect to the country’s fitness value in a given year. The growth rate of the country’s fitness ranking is an easily understood tool to compare the transformations of a country’s productive systems with respect to its competitors. It has been proven a reliable tool in quantifying the country’s relative degree of competitiveness across different years providing a more stable measurement than the raw fitness value 43 .

figure 3

( A ) The Fitness Ranking Growth Rate versus Urbanization Growth Rate. The effect of urbanization growth on the transformation of the economic systems (or vice-versa) is more relevant in low urbanize countries. The dashed lines represent the 95% Confidence Interval (CI) of the linear regression. ( B ) Slope coefficient of a sliding window across \(25\%\) of the countries (corresponding to 36 countries) of its fitness ranking growth rate versus urban population growth rate. The error bar corresponds to the fit’s \(95\%\) confidence interval. The colors follow the Urban Range Scheme.

For each of the four Urban Range quantiles we find a linear relation between the urbanization rate and the Fitness ranking growth rate in Fig.  3 b. Increasing urbanization within lowly urbanized countries is interwoven with increasing Fitness. Meanwhile, the effects are minimal in highly urbanized countries (Urban Range Q3,Q4). We validate the urbanization/fitness relation analyzing a \(25\%\) quantile sliding window on the whole urbanization distribution, which we show in black in Fig.  3 B.

We notice that in many rural economies, the urbanization process affects or has been affected by structural changes in its economic production. (An example are countries such as Uganda, Nepal, Somalia.) On other hand, there are many countries (such as IvoryCoast, Paraguay, Chad) where the urbanization process does not provide improvement in the fitness ranking 44 .

The self-reinforced mechanism between urbanization and fitness reaches a plateau within the urbanized countries (Q3,Q4), where the urbanization does not affect or has not been affected by changes in fitness ranking. In this respect, the resource exports countries manifest a shift toward a negative relation between urbanization and fitness. In fact in countries that are heavily dependent on resource exports, urbanization appears to be concentrated in the cities where the economies consist primarily of non-tradeable services 45 . To support our result we provide the same analysis using instead of the Fitness Ranking metric, the Fitness, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and GDP Ranking respectively (see “ Methods ” section: Urban Range vs Fitness and GDP). We do not find any evidence of relation between the other three metrics and the urbanization rate.

Urban fitness trends

The process of urbanization is often entangled with a country’s industrialization 11 . As countries develop, people move out of rural areas and agricultural activities into urban centers, where they engage in manufacturing products 46 which are more sophisticated with higher complexity. This transformation is outlined by the increasing level of fitness of low urbanized countries that are involved in the urbanization process. To leverage this information and capture its trends, we define the country Urban Fitness \(F_{c}^{\text{ urb }}(t)=F_c(t)*U_c(t)\) ; this is the value of country fitness \(F_c\) weighted by the percentage of urban population \(U_c\) .

figure 4

( A ) Clusters of normalized Urban Fitness Trends. ( B ) Correlation Matrix of the countries urban fitness trends clustered with the Louvain algorithm. ( C ) Geographical cluster distribution. The map in this figure was created using the software QGIS.

We cluster the countries Urban Fitness trends using the Louvain algorithm 47 which is based on their correlation matrix shown in Fig.  4 B. Three clusters emerge with high correlations disentangling the non-trivial geographical relations we show in Fig. 4 A–C.

In Fig.  4 A countries with a clear urbanization trend (in orange) are ones with a stable increase in fitness ranking. Meanwhile the blue cluster contains developed countries, where the urbanization does not provide any new input to the economic development and resource dependent countries, where the urbanization is not only lead by deep structural economic change. These results are in agreement with the Urban Range study in Fig.  3 that show a poor effect of the urbanization on the country fitness, implying that over a given value of urbanization, other factors have a more important role in economic development and growth. Finally, the third cluster (in red) are the countries without any clear trend and are thus uncategorized.

It is well-known that urbanization provides several advantages to the economics of scale and division of labour, boosting productivity and competition. It helps in accessing the labor force and inputting materials to the production process as well as decreasing the geographical distance between firms, reducing transaction costs, and fostering competition 48 . These urbanization advantages 49 together with the appropriate bureaucratic environment 33 , investment in infrastructures 50 and companies market structure 51 , are some of intangible attributes, the capabilities, that a country needs to drive economic growth and innovation 36 . We noticed that the country Fitness, the production and export of goods, is interwoven within the urbanization process during the early stages of country’s economic development and growth. We show that the information carried by WTW can provide a different perspective on analyzing the complex process of urbanization, enlightening the relation between a country’s exports, economic development and its urban growth.

World trade web

The dataset used in this work is the BACI (Base pour l’Analyse du Commerce International) World Trade Database (Gaulier, S. Baci: International trade database at the product-level http://www.cepii.fr/CEPII/fr/publications/wp/abstract.asp?NoDoc=2726 Date of access: 18/01/2021). The data contains information on the trade of 200 different countries for more than 5000 different products, categorized according to the 6-digit code of the Harmonised System 2007 ( http://www.wcoomd.org/ Date of access: 18/01/2021). The products’ sectors follows the UN categorization ( http://unstats.un.org/unsd/cr/registry/regcst.asp?Cl=8 Date of access: 18/01/2021). We create a map between the two systems converting the HS2007 in to the ISIC revision 2 code at 2-digit ( http://www.macalester.edu/research/economics/PAGE/HAVEMAN/Trade.Resources/TradeConcordances.html#FromISIC Date of access: 18/01/2021). We represent the trade relation between the 144 countries \(c\in [1,C]\) and the 1131 products \(p\in [1,P]\) between the years [1995, 2010] throught the bipartite matrix \({\tilde{M}}\) with dimension \((C\times P)\) where each entry \({\tilde{m}}_{c,p}\) measures the export in US dollars. The framework of the Economic-Complexity 19 , 20 , 21 , 22 based on the interaction between countries and products is expressed by the application of the Revealed Comparative Advantage (RCA) 28 threshold over the entries \({\tilde{m}}_{c,p}\) :

Finally, we define the entries of the biadjacency matrix M of the undirected bipartite network analyzed in this work as:

This indicates that the connection (country-product link) is established if and only if the relative RCA is relevant (over the threshold), otherwise it can be ignored. Each row of M represents the export basket of a given country (or its diversification \(k_c\) ), while each column represents the subset of producers of a given product (or its ubiquity \(k_p\) ) 52 .

Urbanization

The data of the urban population from 1995 to 2010 are available at the World Bank database ( https://data.worldbank.org/ Date of access: 18/01/2021).

Fitness and complexity

Fitness and Complexity are a metric for countries and products applied to bipartite binary matrix M of the WTW 19 , 20 , 21 , 22 , 24 . The basic idea of EC is to define a non-linear map through an iterative process which couples the Fitness of countries to the Complexity of products. At every step of the iteration, the Fitness \(F_c\) of a given country c is proportional to the sum of the exported products, weighted by their complexity parameter \(Q_p\) . In particular, the Fitness \(F_c\) for the generic country c and Quality \(Q_p\) for the generic product p at the \(n-\) th step of iteration, are defined as:

where the symbols \(\langle \cdot \rangle\) indicate the average taken over the proper set. The initial condition are taken as \(F_c^0=Q_p^0=1\,\,\forall c\in N_c,\,\forall p\in N_p\) , where \(N_c\) and \(N_p\) are the number respectively of countries and products (the convergence of the algorithm described by Eq. ( 4 ) depends on the shape of the matrix M , as it has been discussed in 43 ).

Bipartite configuration model (BICM)

The Bipartite Configuration Model (BICM), as defined by 34 , 35 , is a null model of general applicability that is able to generate a grandcanonical ensemble of bipartite, undirected, binary networks in which the two layers Country and Products have respectively C and P nodes. The ensemble generate by the BICM constrained the number of connections for each node, on both layers (in our case \(d_c\) and \(u_p\) ) to match, on average, the observed one. Each network \({\mathbf {M}}\) in such ensemble is assigned a probability coefficient:

\(x_c\) and \(y_s\) are the Lagrange multipliers associated to the constrained degrees.

Constraining the ensemble average values of countries and products degree induces the probability that a link exists between country c and industry sector p independently of the other links:

The numerical values of the unknown parameters \({\mathbf {x}}\) and \({\mathbf {y}}\) have to be determined by solving the following system of \(C+P\) equations, which constrains the ensemble average values of countries diversification and products ubiquities to match the real values, \(\langle d_c\rangle =d_c^*,\,c=1\dots C\) and \(\langle u_p\rangle =u_p^*,\,p=1\dots P\) .

Where \(\{d_c^*\}_{c=1}^C\) and \(\{u_p^*\}_{p=1}^S\) are the real degree sequence of countries, and industry sectors respectively, and \(\langle \cdot \rangle\) represents the ensemble average of a given quantity, over the ensemble measure defined by Eq. ( 6 )—as \(\langle d_c\rangle =\sum _sp_{cp}\) and \(\langle u_s\rangle =\sum _cp_{cp}\) . Indicated with an asterisk, “ \(*\) ” are the parameters that satisfy the systems.

Similarity motifs

In the present work we have sampled the grand canonical ensemble of binary, undirected, bipartite networks induced by the BiCM, according to the probability coefficients \(P({\mathbf {M}}|{\mathbf {x}}^*, {\mathbf {y}}^*)\) and calculated the average and variance of the motif \(\mu _{\text{ sim }}\) , define as b-motif6 in 40 .

The Similarity Motif represents the symmetric and complete connections between two countries \(c,c'\) and two industry sectors \(p,p'\) . The number of similarity motifs is:

with \({\fancyscript {Z}}\) is the matrix of dimension ( C ,  C ), that represents the projection of M over the countries. Each entry \({\fancyscript {Z}}_{cc'}\) counts the number of industry sectors in common between the countries c and \(c'\) , it is defined as: \({\fancyscript {Z}}_{cc'}=\sum _{s=1}^S M_{cs}M_{c's}=MM^T\)

This motif represents the co-occurrence of two products in two countries’ export basket within the bipatite matrix of the country exports. The accuracy of the BiCM prediction in reproducing the value of quantity \(\mu _{sim}\) please follows 34 .

figure 5

Slope coefficient of a sliding window across \(25\%\) of the countries (corresponding to 36 countries) of respectively its Fitness Growth Rate ( A )— GDP Growth Rate ( B )— GDP Ranking Growth Rate ( C ) versus Urban Population Growth Rate. The error bar corresponds to the fit’s \(95\%\) confidence interval. The colors follow the Urban Range scheme.

Urban range versus fitness and GDP

To validate our analysis of the relation between the country’s fitness and the urbanization process we analyzed the urbanization growth rate in relation to the growth rate of three different metrics: the country Fitness (Fig.  5 A), country GDP (Fig.  5 B), and country GDP ranking (Fig.  5 C) between 1995 and 2010.

We study the variation of the slope coefficient of a sliding window across \(25\%\) of the countries urban range and the three metrics above. Both the metrics extracted from the GDP do not have statistical significant results. Although the growth rate of fitness in relation with the urbanization growth rate manifests a linear relation (Fig.  5 A) with an \(R^2=0.53\) , as Fig.  3 B, we notice that the fitness ranking is a more reliable tool than the raw fitness value 43 . The fitness ranking provides a more stable metric across each sliding window.

Martin, P. & Ottaviano, G. I. P. Growth and agglomeration. Int. Econ. Rev. 42 , 947–968. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2354.00141 (2001).

Article   Google Scholar  

Buckley, R. M., Annez, P. C. & Spence, M. Urbanization and Growth (The World Bank, 2008).

Duranton, G. Growing through cities in developing countries. The World Bank Research Observer 30 , 39–73. https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/lku006 (2014).

Jacobs, J. The Economy of Cities (Vintage, New York, 2016).

Google Scholar  

Glaeser, E. L., Kallal, H. D., Scheinkman, J. A. & Shleifer, A. Growth in cities. J. Polit. Econ. 100 , 1126–1152. https://doi.org/10.1086/261856 (1992).

Bettencourt, L., Lobo, J., Helbing, D., Kühnert, C. & West, G. Growth, innovation, scaling, and the pace of life in cities. PNAS Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 104 , 7301–7306. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0610172104 (2007).

Article   ADS   CAS   Google Scholar  

Youn, H. et al. Scaling and universality in urban economic diversification. J. R. Soc. Interface 13 , 20150937. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsif.2015.0937 (2016).

Article   PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Ravallion, M., Chen, S. & Sangraula, P. New evidence on the urbanization of global poverty. Popul. Dev. Rev. 33 , 667–701. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2007.00193.x (2007).

Montgomery, M. R. The urban transformation of the developing world. Science 319 , 761. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1153012 (2008).

Article   ADS   CAS   PubMed   Google Scholar  

Petrakos, G. Urbanization and international trade in developing countries. World Dev. 17 , 1269–1277. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(89)90237-4 (1989).

Gollin, D., Jedwab, R. & Vollrath, D. Urbanization with and without industrialization. J. Econ. Growth 21 , 35–70. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-015-9121-4 (2015).

Glaeser, E. L. A world of cities: the causes and consequences of urbanization in poorer countries. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 12 , 1154–1199. https://doi.org/10.1111/jeea.12100 (2014).

Ades, A. F. & Glaeser, E. L. Trade and circuses: explaining urban giants. Q. J. Econ. 110 , 195–227. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118515 (1995).

Article   MATH   Google Scholar  

Davis, J. C. & Henderson, J. Evidence on the political economy of the urbanization process. J. Urban Econ. 53 , 98–125. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0094-1190(02)00504-1 (2003).

Henderson, V. The urbanization process and economic growth: the so-what question*. J. Econ. Growth 8 , 47–71. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1022860800744 (2003).

Fujita, M. & Thisse, J.-F. Does geographical agglomeration foster economic growth? and who gains and loses from it?. Jpn. Econ. Rev. 54 , 121–145. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-5876.00250 (2003).

Article   MathSciNet   Google Scholar  

Krugman, P. R. Geography an Trade (MIT Press, Cambridge, 1993).

Krugman, P. & Elizondo, R. L. Trade policy and the third world metropolis. J. Dev. Econ. 49 , 137–150, https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(95)00055-0 (1996). 

Hidalgo, C. A. & Hausmann, R. The building blocks of economic complexity. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 106 , 10570–10575. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0900943106 (2009).

Article   ADS   PubMed   Google Scholar  

Tacchella, A., Cristelli, M., Caldarelli, G., Gabrielli, A. & Pietronero, L. A new metrics for countries’ fitness and products’ complexity. Sci. Rep. 2 , 723. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep00723 (2012).

Article   ADS   CAS   PubMed   PubMed Central   MATH   Google Scholar  

Cristelli, M., Gabrielli, A., Tacchella, A., Caldarelli, G. & Pietronero, L. Measuring the intangibles: a metrics for the economic complexity of countries and products. PloS One 8 , e70726. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0070726 (2013).

Hidalgo, C. A., Klinger, B., Barabási, A.-L. & Hausmann, R. The product space conditions the development of nations. Science 317 , 482–487. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1144581 (2007).

Tacchella, A., Mazzilli, D. & Pietronero, L. A dynamical systems approach to gross domestic product forecasting. Nat. Phys. 14 , 861. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41567-018-0204-y (2018).

Article   CAS   Google Scholar  

Tacchella, A., Cristelli, M., Caldarelli, G., Gabrielli, A. & Pietronero, L. Economic complexity: conceptual grounding of a new metrics for global competitiveness. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 37 , 1683–1691. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.04.006 (2013).

Article   MathSciNet   MATH   Google Scholar  

Albeaik, S., Kaltenberg, M., Alsaleh, M. & Hidalgo, C. A. Improving the economic complexity index. arXiv preprint arXiv:1707.05826. http://arxiv.org/1707.05826 (2017).

Servedio, V. D. P., Buttà, P., Mazzilli, D., Tacchella, A. & Pietronero, L. A new and stable estimation method of country economic fitness and product complexity. Entropy   20, 783 .  https://doi.org/10.3390/e20100783 (2018).

Sciarra, C., Chiarotti, G., Ridolfi, L. & Laio, F. Reconciling contrasting views on economic complexity. Nat. Commun. 11 , 3352. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-020-16992-1 (2020).

Article   ADS   CAS   PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Balassa, B. Trade liberalisation and “revealed’’ comparative advantage. The Manchester School 33 , 99–123. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9957.1965.tb00050.x (1965).

Hartmann, D., Guevara, M. R., Jara-Figueroa, C., Aristarán, M. & Hidalgo, C. A. Linking economic complexity, institutions, and income inequality. World Dev. 93 , 75–93. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.12.020 (2017).

Pugliese, E., Chiarotti, G. L., Zaccaria, A. & Pietronero, L. Complex economies have a lateral escape from the poverty trap. PloS One 12 , e0168540. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0168540 (2017).

Article   CAS   PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Perc, M. The social physics collective.  Sci. Rep.   9 , 16549. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-019-53300-4 (2019).

Caldarelli, G. et al. A network analysis of countries’ export flows: firm grounds for the building blocks of the economy. PloS One 7 , e47278. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0047278 (2012).

Henderson, J. V., Shalizi, Z. & Venables, A. J. Geography and development. J. Econ. Geogr. 1 , 81–105. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/1.1.81 (2001).

Saracco, F., Di Clemente, R., Gabrielli, A. & Squartini, T. Randomizing bipartite networks: the case of the world trade web. Sci. Rep. 5 , 10595. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep10595 (2015).

Saracco, F., Di Clemente, R., Gabrielli, A. & Squartini, T. Detecting early signs of the 2007–2008 crisis in the world trade. Sci. Rep. 6 , 30286. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep30286 (2016).

Saracco, F., Di Clemente, R., Gabrielli, A. & Pietronero, L. From innovation to diversification: a simple competitive model. PloS One 10 , e0140420. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0140420 (2015).

Tacchella, A., Di Clemente, R., Gabrielli, A. & Pietronero, L. The build-up of diversity in complex ecosystems. arXiv preprint arXiv:1609.03617. http://arxiv.org/1609.03617 (2016).

van Lidth de Jeude, J., Di Clemente, R., Caldarelli, G., Saracco, F. & Squartini, T. Reconstructing mesoscale network structures. Complexity . https://doi.org/10.1155/2019/5120581 (2019).

Gualdi, S., Cimini, G., Primicerio, K., Di Clemente, R. & Challet, D. Statistically validated network of portfolio overlaps and systemic risk. Sci. Rep. 6 , 39467. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep39467 (2016).

Simmons, B. I. et al. bmotif: a package for motif analyses of bipartite networks. Methods Ecol. Evol. 10 , 695–701. https://doi.org/10.1111/2041-210X.13149 (2019).

Saracco, F. et al. Inferring monopartite projections of bipartite networks: an entropy-based approach. New J. Phys. 19 , 053022. https://doi.org/10.1088/1367-2630/aa6b38 (2017).

Article   ADS   Google Scholar  

Bertinelli, L. & Black, D. Urbanization and growth. J. Urban Econ. 56 , 80–96. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2004.03.003 (2004).

Pugliese, E., Zaccaria, A. & Pietronero, L. On the convergence of the fitness-complexity algorithm. Eur. Phys. J. Spec. Top. 225 , 1893–1911. https://doi.org/10.1140/epjst/e2015-50118-1 (2016).

Gindelsky, R. J. L. C. M. Demography, Urbanization and Development: Rural Push, Urban Pull and... Urban Push? (The World Bank, 2015). https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-7333 .

Gollin, D., Jedwab, R. & Vollrath, D. Urbanization with and without industrialization. J. Econ. Growth 21 , 35–70. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-015-9121-4 (2016).

Michaels, G., Rauch, F. & Redding, S. J. Urbanization and structural transformation *. Q. J. Econ. 127 , 535–586. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjs003 (2012).

Blondel, V. D., Guillaume, J.-L., Lambiotte, R. & Lefebvre, E. Fast unfolding of communities in large networks. J. Stat. Mech. Theory Exp. 2008 , P10008. https://doi.org/10.1088/1742-5468/2008/10/p10008 (2008).

Turok, I. & McGranahan, G. Urbanization and economic growth: the arguments and evidence for Africa and Asia. Environ. Urban. 25 , 465–482. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956247813490908 (2013).

Verona, G. & Ravasi, D. Unbundling dynamic capabilities: an exploratory study of continuous product innovation. Ind. Corporate Change 12 , 577–606. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/12.3.577 (2003).

Esfahani, H. S. & Ramirez, M. T. Institutions, infrastructure, and economic growth. J. Dev. Econ. 70 , 443–477. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(02)00105-0 (2003).

Di Clemente, R., Chiarotti, G. L., Cristelli, M., Tacchella, A. & Pietronero, L. Diversification versus specialization in complex ecosystems. PLoS One 9 , e112525. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112525 (2014).

Hausmann, R. & Hidalgo, C. Country diversification, product ubiquity, and economic divergence. SSRN Electron. J. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1724722 (2010).

Download references

Acknowledgements

Riccardo Di Clemente as Newton International Fellow of the Royal Society acknowledges support from the Royal Society, the British Academy, and the Academy of Medical Sciences (Newton International Fellowship, NF170505). The authors would like to thank Fabio Saracco, Enrico Ubaldi, Bernardo Monechi, Andrea Zaccaria, Andrea Gabrielli, Luciano Pietronero and Marta C. González for the insightful discussions and comments.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Computer Sciences, University of Exeter, Exeter, EX4 4QF, UK

Riccardo Di Clemente

Centre for Advanced Spatial Analysis, University College London, London, W1T 4TJ, UK

Riccardo Di Clemente & Michael Batty

MindEarth, 2502, Biel/Bienne, Switzerland

Emanuele Strano

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

R.D.C. and E.S. designed the study and performed the research. R.D.C. analyzed the data and generated the plots, E.S. created the Map. R.D.C., E.S. and M.B. wrote the paper. All the authors gave the final approval for the publication.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Riccardo Di Clemente .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The authors declare no competing interest. The corresponding author is responsible for submitting a competing interests statement on behalf of all authors of the paper.

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Di Clemente, R., Strano, E. & Batty, M. Urbanization and economic complexity. Sci Rep 11 , 3952 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-021-83238-5

Download citation

Received : 05 November 2020

Accepted : 24 January 2021

Published : 17 February 2021

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-021-83238-5

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

This article is cited by

Does financial openness matter for economic transformation in sub-saharan africa.

  • Valentine Soumtang Bime
  • Dieudonné Mignamissi
  • Agathe Cassandra Koumis Ngagni

Economic Change and Restructuring (2024)

Income Inequality in Africa: Exploring the Interaction Between Urbanization and Governance Quality

  • Toyo Amègnonna Marcel Dossou

Social Indicators Research (2023)

Revisiting the Relationship Between Urbanization and Economic Development in China Since the Reform and Opening-up

  • Longwu Liang
  • Mingxing Chen

Chinese Geographical Science (2022)

Comparing alternatives to the fixed degree sequence model for extracting the backbone of bipartite projections

  • Zachary P. Neal
  • Rachel Domagalski
  • Bruce Sagan

Scientific Reports (2021)

By submitting a comment you agree to abide by our Terms and Community Guidelines . If you find something abusive or that does not comply with our terms or guidelines please flag it as inappropriate.

Quick links

  • Explore articles by subject
  • Guide to authors
  • Editorial policies

Sign up for the Nature Briefing: AI and Robotics newsletter — what matters in AI and robotics research, free to your inbox weekly.

research paper on urban economics

Urban Dynamics and Growth: Advances in Urban Economics: Volume 266

Table of contents, list of contributors, the theoretical and methodological toolbox of urban economics: from and towards where, urban scale economies: statics and dynamics, beyond optimal city size: theory and evidence reconsidered, spatial externalities and the urban economy, uncertainty social capital and community governance: the city as a milieu, land-use, transportation and urban development, transport systems and urban equilibrium, intra-metropolitan agglomeration, information technology and polycentric urban development, dual earners, urban labour markets and housing demand, land use regulation and its impact on welfare, spatial interaction models: from the gravity to the neural network approach, commuting: the contribution of search theory, ethnic concentration and human capital formation, advanced insights in central place theory, the city system paradigm: new frontiers, the city network paradigm: theory and empirical evidence, dynamic urban models: agglomeration and growth, new economic geography explanations of urban and regional agglomeration, agglomeration and knowledge diffusion, innovation and the growth of cities, cities and business, strengthening municipal fiscal autonomy through intergovernmental transfers, urban quality of life and public policy: a survey, policy issues in the urban south, urban policy in a global economy.

  • Peter Nijkamp

We’re listening — tell us what you think

Something didn’t work….

Report bugs here

All feedback is valuable

Please share your general feedback

Join us on our journey

Platform update page.

Visit emeraldpublishing.com/platformupdate to discover the latest news and updates

Questions & More Information

Answers to the most commonly asked questions here

urban-economics-logo-2020

Publications in peer-reviewed academic journals

AIn is the normalised Article Influence score, obtained from Eigenfactor.org . AIp is the corresponding Article Influence percentile, with 100 being the best journal in the field of economics and 0 the worst

Working papers

Other papers.

Journal of Urban Economics

research paper on urban economics

Subject Area and Category

  • Economics and Econometrics
  • Urban Studies

Academic Press Inc.

Publication type

00941190, 10959068

Information

How to publish in this journal

research paper on urban economics

The set of journals have been ranked according to their SJR and divided into four equal groups, four quartiles. Q1 (green) comprises the quarter of the journals with the highest values, Q2 (yellow) the second highest values, Q3 (orange) the third highest values and Q4 (red) the lowest values.

The SJR is a size-independent prestige indicator that ranks journals by their 'average prestige per article'. It is based on the idea that 'all citations are not created equal'. SJR is a measure of scientific influence of journals that accounts for both the number of citations received by a journal and the importance or prestige of the journals where such citations come from It measures the scientific influence of the average article in a journal, it expresses how central to the global scientific discussion an average article of the journal is.

Evolution of the number of published documents. All types of documents are considered, including citable and non citable documents.

This indicator counts the number of citations received by documents from a journal and divides them by the total number of documents published in that journal. The chart shows the evolution of the average number of times documents published in a journal in the past two, three and four years have been cited in the current year. The two years line is equivalent to journal impact factor ™ (Thomson Reuters) metric.

Evolution of the total number of citations and journal's self-citations received by a journal's published documents during the three previous years. Journal Self-citation is defined as the number of citation from a journal citing article to articles published by the same journal.

Evolution of the number of total citation per document and external citation per document (i.e. journal self-citations removed) received by a journal's published documents during the three previous years. External citations are calculated by subtracting the number of self-citations from the total number of citations received by the journal’s documents.

International Collaboration accounts for the articles that have been produced by researchers from several countries. The chart shows the ratio of a journal's documents signed by researchers from more than one country; that is including more than one country address.

Not every article in a journal is considered primary research and therefore "citable", this chart shows the ratio of a journal's articles including substantial research (research articles, conference papers and reviews) in three year windows vs. those documents other than research articles, reviews and conference papers.

Ratio of a journal's items, grouped in three years windows, that have been cited at least once vs. those not cited during the following year.

Evolution of the percentage of female authors.

Evolution of the number of documents cited by public policy documents according to Overton database.

Evoution of the number of documents related to Sustainable Development Goals defined by United Nations. Available from 2018 onwards.

Scimago Journal & Country Rank

Leave a comment

Name * Required

Email (will not be published) * Required

* Required Cancel

The users of Scimago Journal & Country Rank have the possibility to dialogue through comments linked to a specific journal. The purpose is to have a forum in which general doubts about the processes of publication in the journal, experiences and other issues derived from the publication of papers are resolved. For topics on particular articles, maintain the dialogue through the usual channels with your editor.

Scimago Lab

Follow us on @ScimagoJR Scimago Lab , Copyright 2007-2024. Data Source: Scopus®

research paper on urban economics

Cookie settings

Cookie Policy

Legal Notice

Privacy Policy

  • Hirsh Health Sciences
  • Webster Veterinary
  • Tisch Library/ SMFA Library/ Lilly Library

Economics 127: Urban Economics

Start with econlit, finding census data, literature reviews, other economics & social science indexes for urban economics, other general and u.s. government publication indexes, working papers in economics, selected newspapers, journals & magazines.

  • Demographics & Statistics
  • Citation Help

Rank Think Tanks by Quality

  • Think Tanks and Civil Society Program The Think Tanks and Civil Societies Program (TTCSP) at the International Relations Program, University of Pennsylvania conducts research on the role policy institutes play in governments and in civil societies around the world.
  • 2016 Global Go To Think Tank Index Report
  • EconLit The American Economic Association's bibliography. Start here for scholarly economic papers.
  • Social Explorer Decennial census & ACS data from 1790-present with mapping and data download capability. more... less... Type: Longitudinal, Cross-Sectional Region: U.S Unit Level: Tract, County, State, Region
  • Social Explorer Tutorial Exercise
  • Policy Map Web-based GIS program including census and ACS data, demographics, home sale statistics, health data, mortgage trends, school performance scores and labor data like unemployment, crime statistics and city crime rates.
  • Policy Map Tutorial
  • Annual Reviews
  • Oxford Bibliographies Online Authoritative research guides. Combining features of annotated bibliographies and encyclopedias, this resource guides researchers to scholarship across a wide variety of subjects.
  • ABI Inform Global. 1971- . This scholarly business periodicals database comprises nearly 1400 North American sources to provide information on advertising, economics, human resources, finance, marketing, computers and more. Includes international sources too.
  • PAIS International Public affairs, public and social policies, international relations - journal articles, books, government documents, statistics, grey literature, research reports, conference papers, microfiche, Internet material, etc. more... less... Index to articles, books, conference proceedings, government documents, book chapters, and statistical directories about public affairs and international relations.
  • Urban Studies & Planning: Sage Journals Online Search from a selection of Sage journals on urban studies and planning
  • Web of Science
  • International Bibliography of the Social Sciences 1951- . The IBSS has more than two million references to articles and books going back to 1951 in the social sciences. It is produced by the London School of Economics and Political Science. Compliments EconLit and PAIS.
  • Social Sciences Citation Index. 1956- . The Social Sciences Citation Index is a multidisciplinary index to the journal literature of the social sciences. You can search both this index and the Arts & Humanities Citation Index together.
  • LexisNexis Academic Includes the text of articles from major American newspapers and regional papers, statistics, company financial information, country and state profiles, and medical information.
  • Congressional Publications A major online resource for information on all aspects of Congressional work. Includes hearing transcripts, committee reports, bills, CRS Reports, the Congressional Record, the Federal Register, the Code of Federal Regulations, and public laws.
  • RePEc (Research Papers in Economics) This resource is a collaborative effort of over 100 volunteers in 41 countries to enhance the dissemination of research in economics. The heart of the project is a decentralized database of working papers, journal articles and software components. Provides full-text access to many working papers.
  • RePEc: Urban & Real Estate Economics New working papers in the area of Urban & Real Estate Economics
  • RePEc: Economic Geography New working papers in the area of Economic Geography
  • Human Development Research Papers From the Human Development Report of 2009: Overcoming barriers: Human mobility and development
  • NBER Working Papers. The National Bureau of Economic Research Working Papers are available now on line going back to November of 1994. Aimed at professional economists, these papers represent the original research of more than 600 leading scholars in their fields.
  • CEPR (Centre for Economic Policy Research) Discussion Papers. The CEPR publishes over 250 Discussion Papers each year. CEPR Discussion Papers are the primary method for the distribution of research carried out by the Centre, and represent timely and original thinking on important issues in economics.
  • WebEc No longer operating, this is an early attempt to categorize free information in economics on the internet, including the List of Economics Journals.
  • Access Magazine Click on the Archive link to get to previous issues.
  • Cityscape 1994- . Indexed in EconLit.
  • Housing Policy Debate. 1990- . Indexed in EconLit.
  • New York Times. 1851-three years before current date. Includes full-text and full-image articles. Does not include freelance written articles or copyrighted materials. You will need to use the NYT on microfilm to get the complete article.
  • Wall Street Journal. 1984- . ProQuest provides full-text access.
  • The Economist 1997 to the present
  • The Economist: Historical Archive 1843-2014 Search the Economist as far back in history as you like.
  • CityLab "Through original reporting, sharp analysis, and visual storytelling, CityLab informs and inspires the people who are creating the cities of the future—and those who want to live there."
  • Next: Books >>

Help with Research

Profile Photo

Related Research Guides

  • Economics by David Fristrom Last Updated Feb 9, 2024 648 views this year
  • Last Updated: Feb 9, 2024 12:45 PM
  • URL: https://researchguides.library.tufts.edu/Economics127

Economic and Urban Dynamics: Investigating Socioeconomic Status and Urban Density as Moderators of Mobile Wallet Adoption in Smart Cities

  • Conference paper
  • First Online: 15 May 2024
  • Cite this conference paper

research paper on urban economics

  • Pawan Kumar   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0003-4892-6374 12 ,
  • Reepu   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-5607-9825 12 &
  • Rajinder Kaur   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-7049-0434 12  

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Networks and Systems ((LNNS,volume 948))

Included in the following conference series:

  • International Conference on Smart Computing and Communication

This research paper examines the complex correlation between socioeconomic factors, urban density, and the acceptance of mobile wallet technology in smart cities. The study investigates how socioeconomic status and urban density influence the adoption of mobile wallets. Smart cities have experienced a significant increase in the adoption of mobile payment solutions such as Apple Pay and Google Pay, noted for their technological innovation and ability to enhance living standards. These digital payment platforms provide ease, security, and efficiency, revolutionising how individuals engage in financial transactions and navigate urban environments. The study examines the many aspects that impact this phenomenon, focusing on the significance of comprehending how socioeconomic status and urban density influence the acceptance of mobile wallets. The study utilises a meticulous research technique, which involves evaluating the reliability and validity of constructs, analysing heterotrait-monotrait (HTMT) ratios, conducting tests for discriminant validity, and doing variance inflation factor (VIF) analysis. These measures are taken to ensure the strength and reliability of the report’s conclusions. The research’s importance is further supported by model fit statistics and hypothesis testing conducted through bootstrapping. The results emphasise that the inclusion of mobile wallet functions, the legal framework, and the development of smart city infrastructure have a substantial influence on the acceptance of mobile wallets. However, the impact of urban density on mobile wallet adoption is more intricate and multifaceted. This study provides significant insights into the dynamic field of technology uptake in urban regions, with implications for politicians, entrepreneurs, and urban planners seeking to promote financial inclusion and technological integration in smart cities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Coros MM, Popescu D, Pop I, Gheorghe G (2023) Smart city, smart tourism. Remoeling Businesses for sustainable development, pp 167–188

Google Scholar  

Polzonetti A, Sagratella M (2018) Smart city and green development. Challenges and opportunities in the digital era, 11195, pp 191–204

Popov EV (2019) Econotronics of a smart city. In: Proceedings of the 1st international scientific conference modern management trends and the digital economy: from regional development to global economic growth vol 81, pp 52–56

Dameri RP, Ricciardi F, D’Auria B (2014) Knowledge and intellectual capital in smart city. In: Proceedings of the 15th European conference on knowledge management (ECKM 2014), vol 1–3, pp 250–257

Jucevicius R, Patasiene I, Patasius M (2014) Digital dimension of smart city: critical analysis. In: 19th international scientific conference economics and management vol 156, pp 146–150

Gorodnova NV, Rozhentsov IS, Peshkova AA (2019) Modeling of smart city concept in Russia. In: Education excellence and innovation management through vision 2020, pp 729–737

Kos B (2019) Intelligent transport systems (ITS) in smart City. In: Challenges of urban mobility, transport companies and systems, pp 115–126

Shah MN, Nagargoje S, Shah C (2017) Assessment of Ahmedabad (India) and Shanghai (China) on smart city parameters applying the Boyd Cohen smart city wheel. In: Proceedings of the 20th international symposium on advancement of construction management and real estate, pp 111–127

Jin-xiao W (2017) Modeling for the measurement of smart city. In: 2017 24th annual international conference on management science and engineering, pp 511–517

Zhang X (2018) New smart city construction driven by innovation. In: 2018 international conference on education, psychology, and management science (ICEMPS 2018), pp 486–489

Catalin C, Andreea FC, Oana-Maria C (2015) The quality of life within a smart city. In: Innovation management and sustainable economic competitive advantage: from regional development to global growth, I–VI, pp 2739–2745

Ojasalo J (2015) Open service innovation platform in a smart city. In: Proceedings of the 10th European conference on innovation and entrepreneurship (ECIE 2015), pp 521–528

Luberg A, Tammet T, Jaerv P (2011) Smart city: a rule-based tourist recommendation system. In: Information and communication technologies in tourism, pp 51–62

Suryotrisongko H, Kusuma RC, Ginardi RVH (2017) Four-hospitality: friendly smart city design for disability. In: 4th information systems international conference, vol 124, pp 615–623

Jucevicius R, Jucevicius G (2014) From knowledge to smart city: a conceptual study. In: Proceedings of the 15th European conference on knowledge management (ECKM 2014), vol 1–3, pp 508–515

Wang C, David B, Chalon R, Yin C (2016) Dynamic road lane management study a smart city application. Transp Res Part E-Logistics Transp Rev 89:272–287

Israilidis J, Odusanya K, Mazhar M (2019) Knowledge management in smart city development: a systematic review. In: Proceedings of the 20th European conference on knowledge management (ECKM 2019), vol 1–2, pp 1231–1233

Nurulin YR, Skvortsova IV, Kalchenko OA (2019) Energy planning and energy efficiency in smart city areas. In: Innovative economic symposium 2018—milestones and trends of world economy (IES2018), vol 61

Janik A, Ryszko A (2018) Scientific landscape of smart city concept: a bibliometric analysis. Vision 2020: sustainable economic development and application of innovation management, pp 6254–6266

Kumar P, Bhatnagar M, Kaur D, Kaur A (2023) Earth and environmental science green infrastructure—a roadmap towards sustainable development green infrastructure—a roadmap towards sustainable development. IOP Conf Ser 1110(1):012060

Bhatnagar M, Özen E, Taneja S, Grima S, Rupeika-Apoga R (2022) The dynamic connectedness between risk and return in the Fintech market of India: evidence using the GARCH-M approach. Risks 10(11):209

Kwak YH, Lee J (2020) Evolution of Korean smart city programs: challenges and opportunities. In: 2020 IEEE technology and engineering management conference

Feng Y, Tong H (2014) Smart city’s legal governance: supervision of the government & risk prevention-a case study in Xiamen’s construction of tourism-oriented smart city. In: International conference on e-commerce and contemporary economic development (ECED 2014), pp 38–44

Odei-Appiah S, Wiredu G, Adjei JK (2022) Fintech use, digital divide and financial inclusion. Digital Policy Regul Gov 24(5):435–448

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Chandigarh University, Mohali, 140413, India

Pawan Kumar,  Reepu & Rajinder Kaur

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pawan Kumar .

Editor information

Editors and affiliations.

Faculty of Engineering, University of the Ryukyus, Nishihara, Okinawa, Japan

Tomonobu Senjyu

College of Computing, Khon Kaen University, Khon Kaen, Thailand

Chakchai So–In

Global Knowledge Research Foundation, Ahmedabad, Gujarat, India

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2024 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this paper

Cite this paper.

Kumar, P., Reepu, Kaur, R. (2024). Economic and Urban Dynamics: Investigating Socioeconomic Status and Urban Density as Moderators of Mobile Wallet Adoption in Smart Cities. In: Senjyu, T., So–In, C., Joshi, A. (eds) Smart Trends in Computing and Communications. SmartCom 2024 2024. Lecture Notes in Networks and Systems, vol 948. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-97-1329-5_33

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-97-1329-5_33

Published : 15 May 2024

Publisher Name : Springer, Singapore

Print ISBN : 978-981-97-1328-8

Online ISBN : 978-981-97-1329-5

eBook Packages : Intelligent Technologies and Robotics Intelligent Technologies and Robotics (R0)

Share this paper

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

research paper on urban economics

Research Projects

Working Papers

Publications

 Current research Projects

research paper on urban economics

Immigration, Social Outcomes, and Housing Markets

research paper on urban economics

Housing Policy

research paper on urban economics

Economics of Zoning

research paper on urban economics

Amenities and Housing Prices

research paper on urban economics

The Economics of Urban Form

  • Future Students
  • Current Students
  • Faculty/Staff

Stanford Graduate School of Education

News and Media

  • News & Media Home
  • Research Stories
  • School's In
  • In the Media

You are here

70 years after brown v. board of education, new research shows rise in school segregation.

Kids getting onto a school bus

As the nation prepares to mark the 70th anniversary of the landmark U.S. Supreme Court ruling in Brown v. Board of Education , a new report from researchers at Stanford and USC shows that racial and economic segregation among schools has grown steadily in large school districts over the past three decades — an increase that appears to be driven in part by policies favoring school choice over integration.

Analyzing data from U.S. public schools going back to 1967, the researchers found that segregation between white and Black students has increased by 64 percent since 1988 in the 100 largest districts, and segregation by economic status has increased by about 50 percent since 1991.

The report also provides new evidence about the forces driving recent trends in school segregation, showing that the expansion of charter schools has played a major role.  

The findings were released on May 6 with the launch of the Segregation Explorer , a new interactive website from the Educational Opportunity Project at Stanford University. The website provides searchable data on racial and economic school segregation in U.S. states, counties, metropolitan areas, and school districts from 1991 to 2022. 

“School segregation levels are not at pre- Brown levels, but they are high and have been rising steadily since the late 1980s,” said Sean Reardon , the Professor of Poverty and Inequality in Education at Stanford Graduate School of Education and faculty director of the Educational Opportunity Project. “In most large districts, school segregation has increased while residential segregation and racial economic inequality have declined, and our findings indicate that policy choices – not demographic changes – are driving the increase.” 

“There’s a tendency to attribute segregation in schools to segregation in neighborhoods,” said Ann Owens , a professor of sociology and public policy at USC. “But we’re finding that the story is more complicated than that.”

Assessing the rise

In the Brown v. Board decision issued on May 17, 1954, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that racially segregated public schools violated the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment and established that “separate but equal” schools were not only inherently unequal but unconstitutional. The ruling paved the way for future decisions that led to rapid school desegregation in many school districts in the late 1960s and early 1970s.

Though segregation in most school districts is much lower than it was 60 years ago, the researchers found that over the past three decades, both racial and economic segregation in large districts increased. Much of the increase in economic segregation since 1991, measured by segregation between students eligible and ineligible for free lunch, occurred in the last 15 years.

White-Hispanic and white-Asian segregation, while lower on average than white-Black segregation, have both more than doubled in large school districts since the 1980s. 

Racial-economic segregation – specifically the difference in the proportion of free-lunch-eligible students between the average white and Black or Hispanic student’s schools – has increased by 70 percent since 1991. 

School segregation is strongly associated with achievement gaps between racial and ethnic groups, especially the rate at which achievement gaps widen during school, the researchers said.  

“Segregation appears to shape educational outcomes because it concentrates Black and Hispanic students in higher-poverty schools, which results in unequal learning opportunities,” said Reardon, who is also a senior fellow at the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research and a faculty affiliate of the Stanford Accelerator for Learning . 

Policies shaping recent trends 

The recent rise in school segregation appears to be the direct result of educational policy and legal decisions, the researchers said. 

Both residential segregation and racial disparities in income declined between 1990 and 2020 in most large school districts. “Had nothing else changed, that trend would have led to lower school segregation,” said Owens. 

But since 1991, roughly two-thirds of districts that were under court-ordered desegregation have been released from court oversight. Meanwhile, since 1998, the charter sector – a form of expanded school choice – has grown.

Expanding school choice could influence segregation levels in different ways: If families sought schools that were more diverse than the ones available in their neighborhood, it could reduce segregation. But the researchers found that in districts where the charter sector expanded most rapidly in the 2000s and 2010s, segregation grew the most. 

The researchers’ analysis also quantified the extent to which the release from court orders accounted for the rise in school segregation. They found that, together, the release from court oversight and the expansion of choice accounted entirely for the rise in school segregation from 2000 to 2019.

The researchers noted enrollment policies that school districts can implement to mitigate segregation, such as voluntary integration programs, socioeconomic-based student assignment policies, and school choice policies that affirmatively promote integration. 

“School segregation levels are high, troubling, and rising in large districts,” said Reardon. “These findings should sound an alarm for educators and policymakers.”

Additional collaborators on the project include Demetra Kalogrides, Thalia Tom, and Heewon Jang. This research, including the development of the Segregation Explorer data and website, was supported by the Russell Sage Foundation, the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, and the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation.   

More Stories

Students in a classroom in Salinas, CA

⟵ Go to all Research Stories

Get the Educator

Subscribe to our monthly newsletter.

Stanford Graduate School of Education

482 Galvez Mall Stanford, CA 94305-3096 Tel: (650) 723-2109

  • Contact Admissions
  • GSE Leadership
  • Site Feedback
  • Web Accessibility
  • Career Resources
  • Faculty Open Positions
  • Explore Courses
  • Academic Calendar
  • Office of the Registrar
  • Cubberley Library
  • StanfordWho
  • StanfordYou

Improving lives through learning

Make a gift now

  • Stanford Home
  • Maps & Directions
  • Search Stanford
  • Emergency Info
  • Terms of Use
  • Non-Discrimination
  • Accessibility

© Stanford University , Stanford , California 94305 .

Are Markups Driving the Ups and Downs of Inflation?

Sylvain Leduc

Download PDF (158 KB)

FRBSF Economic Letter 2024-12 | May 13, 2024

How much impact have price markups for goods and services had on the recent surge and the subsequent decline of inflation? Since 2021, markups have risen substantially in a few industries such as motor vehicles and petroleum. However, aggregate markups—which are more relevant for overall inflation—have generally remained flat, in line with previous economic recoveries over the past three decades. These patterns suggest that markup fluctuations have not been a main driver of the ups and downs of inflation during the post-pandemic recovery.

In the recovery from the pandemic, U.S. inflation surged to a peak of over 7% in June 2022 and has since declined to 2.7% in March 2024, as measured by the 12-month change in the personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index. What factors have been driving the ups and downs of inflation? Production costs are traditionally considered a main contributor, particularly costs stemming from fluctuations in demand for and supply of goods and services. As demand for their products rises, companies need to hire more workers and buy more intermediate goods, pushing up production costs. Supply chain disruptions can also push up the cost of production. Firms may pass on all or part of the cost increases to consumers by raising prices. Thus, an important theoretical linkage runs from cost increases to inflation. Likewise, decreases in costs should lead to disinflation.

Labor costs are an important factor of production costs and are often useful for gauging inflationary pressures. However, during the post-pandemic surge in inflation, nominal wages rose more slowly than prices, such that real labor costs were falling until early 2023. By contrast, disruptions to global supply chains pushed up intermediate goods costs, contributing to the surge in inflation (see, for example, Liu and Nguyen 2023). However, supply chains have more direct impacts on goods inflation than on services inflation, which also rose substantially.

In this Economic Letter , we consider another factor that might drive inflation fluctuations: changes in firms’ pricing power and markups. An increase in pricing power would be reflected in price-cost markups, leading to higher inflation; likewise, a decline in pricing power and markups could alleviate inflation pressures. We use industry-level measures of markups to trace their evolving impact on inflation during the current expansion. We find that markups rose substantially in some sectors, such as the motor vehicles industry. However, the aggregate markup across all sectors of the economy, which is more relevant for inflation, has stayed essentially flat during the post-pandemic recovery. This is broadly in line with patterns during previous business cycle recoveries. Overall, our analysis suggests that fluctuations in markups were not a main driver of the post-pandemic surge in inflation, nor of the recent disinflation that started in mid-2022.

Potential drivers of inflation: Production costs and markups

To support households and businesses during the pandemic, the Federal Reserve lowered the federal funds rate target to essentially zero, and the federal government provided large fiscal transfers and increased unemployment benefits. These policies boosted demand for goods and services, especially as the economy recovered from the depth of the pandemic.

The increase in overall demand, combined with supply shortages, boosted the costs of production, contributing to the surge in inflation during the post-pandemic recovery. Although labor costs account for a large part of firms’ total production costs, real labor costs were falling between early 2021 and mid-2022 such that the increases in prices outpaced those in nominal wages. This makes it unlikely that labor costs were driving the surge in inflation.

Instead, we focus on another potential alternative driver of inflation that resulted from firms’ ability to adjust prices, known as pricing power. As demand for goods surged early in the post-pandemic recovery, companies may have had a greater ability to raise their prices above their production costs, a gap known as markups. Following a sharp drop in spending at the height of the pandemic, people may have become eager to resume normal spending patterns and hence more tolerant to price increases than in the past. In fact, growth of nonfinancial corporate profits accelerated in the early part of the recovery (see Figure 1), suggesting that companies had increased pricing power. Some studies have pointed to the strong growth in nonfinancial corporate profits in 2021 as evidence that increased markups have contributed to inflation (see, for example, Weber and Wasmer 2023). However, the figure also shows that growth in corporate profits is typically volatile. Corporate profits tend to rise in the early stages of economic recoveries. Data for the current recovery show that the increase in corporate profits is not particularly pronounced compared with previous recoveries.

Figure 1 Profit growth for nonfinancial businesses

research paper on urban economics

More importantly, corporate profits are an imperfect measure of a firm’s pricing power because several other factors can drive changes in profitability. For instance, much of the recent rise in corporate profits can be attributed to lower business taxes and higher subsidies from pandemic-related government support, as well as lower net interest payments due to monetary policy accommodation (Pallazzo 2023).

Instead of relying on profits as a measure of pricing power, we construct direct measures of markups based on standard economic models. Theory suggests that companies set prices as a markup over variable production costs, and that markup can be inferred from the share of a firm’s revenue spent on a given variable production factor, such as labor or intermediate goods. Over the period of data we use, we assume that the specific proportion of a company’s production costs going toward inputs does not change. If the share of a firm’s revenue used for inputs falls, it would imply a rise in the firm’s price-cost margin or markup. In our main analysis, we use industry-level data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) to compute markups based on the share of revenue spent on intermediate inputs. Our results are similar if we instead use the share of revenue going toward labor costs.

We compare the evolution of markups to that of prices, as measured by the PCE price index, since the recovery from the pandemic. In constructing this price index, the BEA takes into account changes in product characteristics (for instance, size) that could otherwise bias the inflation measure by comparing the prices of inherently different products over time. Similarly, based upon standard economic theory, our markup measure implicitly captures changes in those characteristics (see, for example, Aghion et al. 2023).

The post-pandemic evolution of markups

We examine the evolution of markups in each industry since the third quarter of 2020, the start of the post-pandemic recovery. Figure 2 shows that some sectors, such as the motor vehicles and petroleum industries, experienced large cumulative increases in markups during the recovery. Markups also rose substantially in general merchandise, such as department stores, and for other services, such as repair and maintenance, personal care, and laundry services. Since the start of the expansion, markups in those industries rose by over 10%—comparable in size to the cumulative increases over the same period in the core PCE price index, which excludes volatile food and energy components. However, the surge in inflation through June 2022 was broad based, with prices also rising substantially outside of these sectors. Thus, understanding the importance of markups for driving inflation requires a macroeconomic perspective that examines the evolution of aggregate markups across all sectors of the economy.

Figure 2 Cumulative changes in markups for salient industries

research paper on urban economics

The role of aggregate markups in the economy

To assess how much markup changes contribute to movements in inflation more broadly, we use our industry-level measurements to calculate an aggregate markup at the macroeconomic level. We aggregate the cumulative changes in industry markups, applying two different weighting methods, as displayed in Figure 3. In the first method (green line), we match our industry categories to the spending categories in the core PCE price index for ease of comparison; we then use the PCE weights for each category to compute the aggregate markup. Alternatively, we use each industry’s cost weights to compute the aggregate markup (blue line). Regardless of the weighting method, Figure 3 shows that aggregate markups have stayed essentially flat since the start of the recovery, while the core PCE price index (gray line) rose by more than 10%. Thus, changes in markups are not likely to be the main driver of inflation during the recovery, which aligns with results from Glover, Mustre-del-Río, and von Ende-Becker (2023) and Hornstein (2023) using different methodologies or data. Markups also have not played much of a role in the slowing of inflation since the summer of 2022.

Figure 3 Cumulative changes in aggregate markups and prices

research paper on urban economics

Moreover, the path of aggregate markups over the past three years is not unusual compared with previous recoveries. Figure 4 shows the cumulative changes in aggregate markups since the start of the current recovery (dark blue line), alongside aggregate markups following the 1991 (green line), 2001 (yellow line), and 2008 (light blue line) recessions. Aggregate markups have stayed roughly constant throughout all four recoveries.

Figure 4 Cumulative changes of aggregate markups in recoveries

research paper on urban economics

Firms’ pricing power may change over time, resulting in markup fluctuations. In this Letter , we examine whether increases in markups played an important role during the inflation surge between early 2021 and mid-2022 and if declines in markups have contributed to disinflation since then. Using industry-level data, we show that markups did rise substantially in a few important sectors, such as motor vehicles and petroleum products. However, aggregate markups—the more relevant measure for overall inflation—have stayed essentially flat since the start of the recovery. As such, rising markups have not been a main driver of the recent surge and subsequent decline in inflation during the current recovery.

Aghion, Philippe, Antonin Bergeaud, Timo Boppart, Peter J. Klenow, and Huiyu Li. 2023. “A Theory of Falling Growth and Rising Rents.”  Review of Economic Studies  90(6), pp.2,675-2,702.

Glover, Andrew, José Mustre-del-Río, and Alice von Ende-Becker. 2023. “ How Much Have Record Corporate Profits Contributed to Recent Inflation? ” FRB Kansas City Economic Review 108(1).

Hornstein, Andreas. 2023. “ Profits and Inflation in the Time of Covid .” FRB Richmond Economic Brief 23-38 (November).

Liu, Zheng, and Thuy Lan Nguyen. 2023. “ Global Supply Chain Pressures and U.S. Inflation .” FRBSF Economic Letter 2023-14 (June 20).

Palazzo, Berardino. 2023. “ Corporate Profits in the Aftermath of COVID-19 .” FEDS Notes , Federal Reserve Board of Governors, September 8.

Weber, Isabella M. and Evan Wasner. 2023. “Sellers’ Inflation, Profits and Conflict: Why Can Large Firms Hike Prices in an Emergency?” Review of Keynesian Economics 11(2), pp. 183-213.

Opinions expressed in FRBSF Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. This publication is edited by Anita Todd and Karen Barnes. Permission to reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Please send editorial comments and requests for reprint permission to [email protected]

IMAGES

  1. (PDF) URBAN AND REGIONAL ECONOMICS LECTURE NOTE

    research paper on urban economics

  2. Urban Economics course outline

    research paper on urban economics

  3. (PDF) Lectures on Urban Economics by Jan K. Brueckner

    research paper on urban economics

  4. Urban Economics

    research paper on urban economics

  5. Advances in Urban and Regional Economics: An Essay on Urban Economic

    research paper on urban economics

  6. Lectures on Urban Economics Exercises

    research paper on urban economics

VIDEO

  1. Case Study Development of Pondicherry Beach (ARC)

  2. Module-1 Definition and scope of Urban Economics (Part-3) 6 th sem /BA Economics #calicutuniversity

  3. Module -3 |Urban Labour Markets|6 semester| BA Economics| Urban Economics #calicutuniversity

  4. Module-4 |Urbanization in India |Part-2| Urban Economics /6 th sem/ BA Economics #calicutuniversity

  5. Module -1 |Definition and scope of Urban Economics| 6 th sem| BA Economics|Urban Economics

  6. Urban Economics: Why Cities? (Part 1)

COMMENTS

  1. Journal of Urban Economics

    The Journal of Urban Economics provides a focal point for the publication of research papers in the rapidly expanding field of urban economics. It publishes papers of great scholarly merit on a wide range of topics and employing a wide range of approaches to urban economics. The Journal welcomes …. View full aims & scope.

  2. Urbanization and economic complexity

    Economic complexity and urbanization. We represent the WTW as a bipartite network, i.e. by considering the set of world-countries and the set of products as different entities and linking a given ...

  3. History and Urban Economics

    W.Walker Hanlon & Stephan Heblich, 2021. "History and urban economics," Regional Science and Urban Economics, . citation courtesy of. Founded in 1920, the NBER is a private, non-profit, non-partisan organization dedicated to conducting economic research and to disseminating research findings among academics, public policy makers, and business ...

  4. 62890 PDFs

    Explore the latest full-text research PDFs, articles, conference papers, preprints and more on URBAN ECONOMICS. Find methods information, sources, references or conduct a literature review on ...

  5. Urban Economics Lab

    The Journal of Law & Economics, 53(1), 137-165. URBAN ECONOMICS LAB Email: [email protected] X (Twitter): @MIT_uelab Massachusetts Institute of Technology Center for Real Estate 105 Massachusetts Avenue Samuel Tak Lee Bldg. 9-343 Cambridge, MA 02139

  6. Infrastructure and Urban Form

    DOI 10.3386/w28287. Issue Date December 2020. Cities are shaped by transportation infrastructure. Older cities were anchored by waterways. Nineteenth century cities followed the path of streetcars and subways. The 20th century city rebuilt itself around the car. The close connection between transportation and urban form is natural, since cities ...

  7. Urban Economics Lab

    MIT Center for Real Estate Research Paper, (5). Romem, I., & Saiz, A. (2015). The BuildZoom & Urban Economics Lab Index. Technical Document. URBAN ECONOMICS LABEmail: [email protected] (Twitter): @MIT_uelab. Massachusetts Institute of TechnologyCenter for Real Estate 105 Massachusetts AvenueSamuel Tak Lee Bldg. 9-343Cambridge, MA 02139.

  8. Cities as Engines of Opportunities: Evidence from Brazil

    Working Paper 32426. DOI 10.3386/w32426. Issue Date May 2024. Are developing-world cities engines of opportunities for low-wage earners? In this study, we track a cohort of young low-income workers in Brazil for thirteen years to explore the contribution of factors such as industrial structure and skill segregation on upward income mobility. We ...

  9. Urban Dynamics and Growth: Advances in Urban Economics:

    Urban Dynamics and Growth: Advances in Urban Economics | Editors: R. Capello, Peter Nijkamp. Books and journals Case studies Expert Briefings Open Access. Publish with us Advanced search. Urban Dynamics and Growth: Advances in Urban Economics: Volume 266. Subject: Table of contents (27 chapters)

  10. PDF Essays in Urban Economics

    Essays in Urban Economics A dissertation presented by Matthew George Resseger to The Department of Economics in partial ful llment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the subject of Economics Harvard University Cambridge, Massachusetts April 2014.

  11. Urban Economics, City Development and Future Social Challenges

    The findings of this paper show that research on the urban informal economy has grown from 2000 to 2021, which is a 22-year period in which this review paper was based. The main themes of urban economic informality research depict it as a multifaceted system that is constituted by inputs, processes and outputs that have linkages with the formal ...

  12. Urban Economics Lab

    The Urban Economics Lab at MIT focuses on studying economic activity and economic trends in cities. The Lab uses analytical models and big data to understand what makes cities thrive or decline, how housing values are formed and oscillate, and how local politics and social phenomena manifest in the context of increasing global urbanization ...

  13. Papers

    Publications in peer-reviewed academic journals AIn is the normalised Article Influence score, obtained from Eigenfactor.org. AIp is the corresponding Article Influence percentile, with 100 being the best journal in the field of economics and 0 the worst Working papers Other papers

  14. Urbanization and economic growth: the arguments and evidence for Africa

    With the focus of economic research on the relationship between cities/urbanization and productivity/growth, there has been little systematic analysis of the varied forms or composition of urban economic growth. ... "Africa's urban transition and the role of regional collaboration", Human Settlements Working Paper Series, Urban Change 5 ...

  15. Regional Science and Urban Economics

    About the journal. Regional Science and Urban Economics facilitates and encourages high-quality scholarship on important issues in regional and urban economics. It publishes significant contributions that are theoretical or empirical, positive or normative. It solicits original papers with a spatial dimension that …. View full aims & scope.

  16. Systematic Review of Informal Urban Economies

    Amid globalization and market liberalization, urban informality has continued to grow in leaps and bounds in many parts of the world. Against this backdrop, the purpose of this paper is to provide a systematic review of studies conducted on urban economic informality at various geopolitical contexts to provide an update on the current state of knowledge in the urban informal economy-related ...

  17. Journal of Urban Economics

    Scope. The Journal of Urban Economics provides a focal point for the publication of research papers in the rapidly expanding field of urban economics. It publishes papers of great scholarly merit on a wide range of topics and employing a wide range of approaches to urban economics. The Journal welcomes papers that are theoretical or empirical ...

  18. The Streetlight Effect in Data-Driven Exploration

    In our model of the streetlight effect, we predict that when data shines a light on attractive but not optimal projects, it can severely narrow the breadth of exploration and lower individual and group payoffs. We test our predictions in an online lab experiment and show that the availability of data on the true value of one project can lower ...

  19. Articles

    This resource is a collaborative effort of over 100 volunteers in 41 countries to enhance the dissemination of research in economics. The heart of the project is a decentralized database of working papers, journal articles and software components. Provides full-text access to many working papers. RePEc: Urban & Real Estate Economics.

  20. Does industrial sustainable development policy act as a booster for

    Eco‐industrial parks (EIPs), which reduce pollution and transform the industrial sector to be more environmentally benign, represent the industrial sustainable development policy. However, little research has concentrated on its economic effects. We explore the impacts of 93 national demonstration EIPs on urban economic development using time‐varying difference‐in‐difference, based on ...

  21. Economic and Urban Dynamics: Investigating Socioeconomic ...

    This research paper examines the complex correlation between socioeconomic factors, urban density, and the acceptance of mobile wallet technology in smart cities. ... Kaur, R. (2024). Economic and Urban Dynamics: Investigating Socioeconomic Status and Urban Density as Moderators of Mobile Wallet Adoption in Smart Cities. In: Senjyu, T., So-In ...

  22. Urban Economics Lab

    URBAN ECONOMICS LAB Email: [email protected] X (Twitter): @MIT_uelab Massachusetts Institute of Technology Center for Real Estate 105 Massachusetts Avenue Samuel Tak Lee Bldg. 9-343 Cambridge, MA 02139 105 Massachusetts Ave., Cambridge, MA, USA | (617) 253-9129 | [email protected] | Accessibility

  23. 70 years after Brown v. Board of Education, new research shows rise in

    As the nation prepares to mark the 70th anniversary of the landmark U.S. Supreme Court ruling in Brown v.Board of Education, a new report from researchers at Stanford and USC shows that racial and economic segregation among schools has grown steadily in large school districts over the past three decades — an increase that appears to be driven in part by policies favoring school choice over ...

  24. Urban Economics

    Urban Economics. The Urban Economics Working Group studies the economics of cities and the many policies and factors that determine city structure and performance, such as land use restrictions, local labor markets, agglomeration economies, trade, and transportation infrastructure. The latest working group meeting.

  25. Are Markups Driving the Ups and Downs of Inflation?

    These patterns suggest that markup fluctuations have not been a main driver of the ups and downs of inflation during the post-pandemic recovery. In the recovery from the pandemic, U.S. inflation surged to a peak of over 7% in June 2022 and has since declined to 2.7% in March 2024, as measured by the 12-month change in the personal consumption ...

  26. PDF Urban Economics and Entrepreneurship

    In addition, some of the canonical work in urban economics can be interpreted as having an entrepreneurial dimension. For example, in this paper, we will discuss the entrepreneurial aspects of urban economic research on agglomeration in general and on New Economic Geography (NEG) in particular. 1. 1

  27. The Deloitte Global 2024 Gen Z and Millennial Survey

    Download the 2024 Gen Z and Millennial Report. 5 MB PDF. To learn more about the mental health findings, read the Mental Health Deep Dive. The 13th edition of Deloitte's Gen Z and Millennial Survey connected with nearly 23,000 respondents across 44 countries to track their experiences and expectations at work and in the world more broadly.